A failure of the market for college education and on-the-job human capital
Introduction
Human capital is a fundamental determinant of economic performance (growth and inequality). Most individuals spend large amounts of time and money during their early years in order to acquire general human capital through formal education. Credit market imperfections play a crucial role in education decisions, since human capital or labor cannot be pledged as collateral. In fact, conditional on ability, college attendance is strongly increasing in family income and wealth, and, since the mid-1990s, more and more students around the world exhaust government student loan programs and turn to private lenders for additional credit (see, for instance Chapman (2006) and Lochner & Monge-Naranjo (2016)). Post-school training is also key to augmenting and adapting human capital acquired earlier in life to technical and structural changes, in order to decrease unemployment risk, increase wages, and improve career prospects. Firms invest considerable resources in training: Heckman, Lochner, & Taber (1998) estimate that over half of lifetime human capital is obtained through post-school investment, including training within firms. Estimates from Europe typically document that 80 to 90 percent of the training is general in nature, whereas U.S. based studies provide estimates of general training in the vicinity of 60 to 70 percent of all training spells (Barron, Berger, Black, 1999, Booth, Bryan, 2002, Loewenstein, Spletzer, 1997, Loewenstein, Spletzer, 1998, see, for instance,).
Since Becker (1964), economists have argued that, in a competitive labor market, workers capture the full return to their general human capital and, therefore, undertake the efficient investment–provided that they do not face credit constraints. Because workers get the full return to general skills, firms are fully held-up and thereby they do not invest in general human capital. Balmaceda (2005) shows that, when wages are determined by bargaining with outside options instead of inside options, and workers acquire specific skills that are neither complements nor substitutes with general skills, workers underinvest in general skills and firms invest in general skills despite the fact that the market pays workers a wage that fully rewards their productivity. In his setting, when outside options are modeled as inside options, Becker (1964)’s predictions hold. Thus, (Becker, 1964) result hinges on the particular assumption that bargaining with the incumbent firm and employment on the spot market are not mutually exclusive, establishing that rents are independent of general skills.
This paper studies human capital investments by both firms and college students when the labor market is competitive and students face credit constraints. Despite it being perfectly competitive, the labor market fails to provide incentives for first-best investments. This implies that investments are inefficiently low and this has distributive consequences: human capital underinvestment is most severe among high-ability low-income students. Long-term contracts that optimally set a downward rigid wage floor, together with privately provided income-contingent loans (ICLs), partially alleviate the inefficiency and distributive consequences of the market failure uncovered here. This calls for government interventions that take place in the form of merit-based firm subsidies and government student loans (GSL).
Section 3 proposes a model with pre- and post-school complementary investment in general human capital in a competitive labor market with endogenous separations due to match-specific shocks.2 The model comprises three periods: in the first period, college students acquire human capital through college education; in the second period, each young worker-firm pair negotiates a long-term contract that specifies the first-period wage and a downward rigid wage floor applicable when the worker becomes old. Then, firms decide how much to invest in the general skills of young workers. At the end of this period, a match-specific shock is realized. Finally, in the last period, each firm-old worker pair renegotiates the contract terms if they so chose, the firm decides whether to fire the worker or not, and the old worker simultaneously decides whether to stay or quit. Wages are determined by Rubinstein (1982) alternating offers bargaining game with outside options, and the restriction that the wage cannot be lower than the wage floor established in the long-term contract. Workers are initially endowed with personal/family wealth that determines, together with credit protection laws and the inalienability of human capital, their access to private and government student loans. Private loans are subject to moral hazard, while government loans have an exogenous upper limit and can only be spent on educational expenses.
Given that contract terms can be renegotiated when the worker becomes old, the firm anticipates that it is going to be held-up with positive probability and thereby chooses an inefficiently low level of investment. The firm’s investment rises with the young worker’s amount of human capital, since college and post-college human capital are complements, and the former decreases the probability of the worker leaving the incumbent firm. When workers are young, firms and workers negotiate a wage for the current and next period. Because firms compete for young workers in a Bertrand-like fashion, the first-period wage must be such that total career wages are equal to total career productivity minus the firm’s investment costs. This implies that competition allows the student to receive the full return to their investment in general human capital. In equilibrium, the firm sets a positive wage floor, since this maximizes total career wages. This stems from the fact that the firm underinvests in general human capital, and a wage floor allows the firm to get a full marginal return to human capital with positive probability, which provides the firm with stronger incentives to invest in general skills. Thus, setting downward rigid wages is welfare-increasing, despite the fact that the labor market is competitive. This result is interesting in its own right, since it is contrary to existing economic theory, which suggests that price regulations in competitive markets are always welfare-decreasing.
In spite of the fact that students anticipate that they will get the full return to their investment in formal education, in the unique sub-game perfect equilibrium, they underinvest in general human capital since they anticipate the firm will underinvest and investments are complements. This underinvestment is exacerbated when students are credit-constrained, and this not only harms an individual’s lifetime accumulation of general human capital since less college education is undertaken, but also reduces the amount of investment to be received from future employers. Thus, workers are faced with lower expected total career productivity and wages. High-skill low-wealth students are the ones most harmed by this market failure.
Because competitive labor markets fail to provide first-best incentives to invest in general human capital, and this affects students with different initial skills and wealth differently, a government intervention is required. In Section 6, we show that the first-best efficient investment profile can be implemented by providing firms with subsidies and by GSLs. A firm’s subsidy that pays a share of the investment costs, and is made contingent on initial skills, implements the first-best investment profile. Alternatively, the subsidy can be made contingent in the firm’s investment in human capital, which facilitates its implementation. We also show that fully enforceable GSLs with positive upper limits that may or may not be contingent on students’ means is required. Hence, subsidies to human capital, together with private and publicly-provided loans for credit-constrained students, create a virtuous cycle; subsidies and GSL increase human capital investments, which results in better access to private loans, which in turn, increase investments in human capital even further.
In the next section, we provide a literature review. In Section 3, the model is presented. In the following section, the determination of old-.workers’ wage is studied, and the difference between treating outside offers as outside versus inside options is discussed. Also the cooperative benchmark is presented. In Section 5, the sub-game perfect equilibrium is derived. In the following section, Section 6, we derive the firm’s human-capital subsidies and the GSL’s limit that implements the first-best efficient investment in human capital, and discuss the empirical evidence regarding subsidies and student loans. In the last section, we present concluding remarks.
Section snippets
Literature review
This paper relates to three different human capital literature strands: the one on investment in general human capital, literature concerned with the financing of human capital investments and its consequences, and the one that studies different contractual provisions designed to deal with incentives for human capital investments. The first vein is well-known and, for the sake of brevity, will not be part of this discussion, except for a brief discussion of Balmaceda (2005), whose model is
Set-up
We consider a three-period model between homogeneous firms and heterogeneous workers , both risk neutral. All firms have access to the same constant returns to scale technology; i.e. total productivity is equal to the sum of each worker’s productivity.7
Period 3 wage determination
When and , in the unique sub-game perfect equilibrium renegotiation does not take place (interval with blue legend Wage floor paid in Fig. 2). This is because renegotiation will always make one of the two parties worse-off, and no player can credibly break the relationship, because their outside option is lower than, or equal to what they get within the current employment relationship. When , the relationship is terminated by the firm, since the wage cannot be downwardly
The sub-game perfect equilibrium
In this section, we derive the equilibrium by backward induction. The Nash equilibrium in the sub-game that begins in period 3 was already derived in sub-Section 4.1.
Subsidies and GSL limit: implementing the first-best
So far, we have shown that firms and students underinvest in general human capital and this problem is more severe for high-skill low-income students.30 Thus, a priori, increases in
Conclusions
This paper shows that competitive labor markets fail to provide first-best incentives to both college students and firms. This market failure has the strongest impact on high-ability low-income students. Since they wish to invest a large amount and are credit-constrained, their degree of underinvestment is higher, and firms respond by also investing less in them, which in turn decreases their access to private loans even further. As a result, this market failure, combined with credit
References (75)
Durable goods theory for real world markets
Journal of Economic Perspectives
(2003)- et al.
The effectiveness of active labor market policies: A meta-analysis
Journal of Economic Surveys
(2019) Optimal taxation and human capital policies over the life cycle
Journal of Political Economy
(2017)Promotion, turnover, earnings, and firm-sponsored training
Journal of Labor Economics
(2004)- et al.
Investments, holdup, and the form of market contracts
The American Economic Review
(1993) - et al.
Delayed formal on-the-job training
Industrial and Labor Relations Review
(1997) Risky human capital and alternative bankruptcy regimes for student loans
Journal of Human Capital
(2011)- et al.
The limited influence of unemployment on the wage bargain
American Economic Review
(2008) - et al.
Education policy and intergenerational transfers in equilibrium
Journal of Political Economy
(2019) - et al.
Providing employers with incentives to train low-skilledworkers: Evidence from the uk employer training pilots
Journal of Labor Economics
(2011)
Beyond becker: Training in imperfect labor markets
Economic Journal
The structure of wages and investment in general training
Journal of Political Economy
Training and labour market flexibility: Is there a trade-off?
British Journal of Industrial Relations,
Training in Europe
Journal of the European Economic Association
Human capital development and parental investment in india
Review of Economic Studies
The determinants of human capital formation during the early years of life: Theory, measurement, and policies
Journal of the European Economic Association
Firm-sponsored general training
Journal of Labor Economics
Do workers pay for on-the-job training?
Journal of Human Resources
Workplace training in Europe
IZA Discussion Papers 1640
Human capital
New York: Columbia University Press
The changing role of family income and ability in determining educational achievement
Journal of Human capital
The nash bargaining solution in economic modeling
Rand Journal of Economics
Human capital investment: The returns from education and training to the individual, the firm and the economy
Fiscal Studies
Job-related formal training: Who receives it and what is it worth?
Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics
Who pays for general training? New evidence for British men and women
IZA Discussion Papers 486
Is wage compression a necessary condition for firm-financed general training?
Oxford Economic Papers
A new test of borrowing constraints for education
The Review of Economic Studies
On the complementarity between education and training in Europe
IZA Discussion Papers 309
The dynamics of educational attainment for black, hispanic, and white males
Journal of Political Economy
Estimation of educational borrowing constraints using returns to schooling
Journal of Political Economy
Active labour market policy evaluations: A meta-analysis*
The Economic Journal
What works? A meta analysis of recent active labor market program evaluations
Journal of the European Economic Association
The evidence on credit constraints in post–secondary schooling
Economic Journal
Human capital investment under asymmetric information: The Pigovian conjecture revisited
Journal of Labor Economics
Chapter 25 income contingent loans for higher education: International reforms
Search, matching, and training
Review of Economic Dynamics
Formulating, identifying and estimating the technology of cognitive and noncognitive skill formation
Journal of Human Resources
Cited by (2)
Heterogeneity in the Causal Link between FDI, Globalization and Human Capital: New Empirical Evidence Using Threshold Regressions
2022, Sustainability (Switzerland)Model of Human Capital Formation in the Context of Digitalization to Ensure the Economic Security of the State
2022, Lecture Notes in Information Systems and Organisation
Recommended articles (6)
- Research article
Gender differences in leaving questions blank on high-stakes standardized tests
Economics of Education Review, Volume 84, 2021, Article 102162 - Research article
The effect of technology funding on school-level student proficiency
Economics of Education Review, Volume 84, 2021, Article 102151 - Research article
Are girls always good for boys? Short and long term effects of school peers’ gender
Economics of Education Review, Volume 84, 2021, Article 102150 - Research article
The impact of attending an independent upper secondary school: Evidence from Sweden using school ranking data
Economics of Education Review, Volume 84, 2021, Article 102148 - Research article
Does domestic violence jeopardize the learning environment of peers within the school? Peer effects of exposure to domestic violence in urban Peru
Economics of Education Review, Volume 84, 2021, Article 102147 - Research article
Centralized college admissions and student composition
Economics of Education Review, Volume 85, 2021, Article 102184
- 1
I would like to express my gratitude to participants at the regular CEA and UDP regular seminars and the MIPP Macro-Labor Workshop, 2019. Special thanks to a referee for their insightful comments. I would also like to thank the financial support of the Engineering Institute of Complex Systems, grants ANID AFB 180003, and Institute for Research in Market Imperfections and Public Policy, MIPP, grant ICM IS130002.